Home / Blogs

Exploring the Various Options of Private gTLD Auctions

Protect your privacy:  Get NordVPN  [73% off 2-year plans, 3 extra months]

Now that ICANN’s Last Resort Auctions are becoming an imminent reality, more and more applicants with gTLDs in contention are coming to the conclusion that they would be better off in a private auction. As a result, there is a renewed discussion of the various approaches that have been proposed. Interesting new suggestions have also been made within the gTLD applicant community.

Innovative Auction‘s offering, the Applicant Auction, has been used to resolve contention for 21 gTLDs to date, and we have good reasons for continuing to recommend the approach taken in these past auctions.

However, we are open to implementing other auction designs applicants would like us to run for them, and we have explored other options. We are sharing our conclusions from these efforts to help applicants decide what works best for them.

In designing a private auction, several different decisions have to be made:

  • Auction Design—Sealed Bid? Ascending Clock?
  • What happens with the winner’s payment?
  • How does the settlement process enforce the auction outcome?

Auction Designs

In Sealed Bid auctions, each bidder makes a one-time bid. The highest bidder wins, and pays either the price they bid (a “First Price” auction) or the second highest price (”Second Price” auction). A First Price auction is easy to understand, but difficult to bid in—the best bidding strategy involves trying to guess what the others will bid and then bidding just a little bit more. Bid too much, and you overpay if you win. Bid too little and you won’t win—and, worse, possibly watch someone else win for less that you were willing to pay. (Economists call this particular outcome “inefficient”—it fails to reach a fundamental goal of an auction, which is to put a good in the hands of whoever values it the most.)

A Second Price auction doesn’t have that problem—you can bid as much as you think the gTLD is worth to you, and if you win, you only pay the amount necessary to win. This simplifies the bidding strategy and results in a more efficient outcome. This is one of the reasons why ICANN chose a Second Price auction.

Live Auctions are a kind of second price auction—when only one bidder is left, the auction ends, and the winner pays the second highest price (plus a small bidding increment). However, a key difference between a traditional live auction and an online auction is that there is more excitement. One skill a traditional auctioneer has is to engage bidders emotionally and viscerally in a competitive live auction environment to induce competition-maximizing revenues for the seller.

Most Online Auctions (for example, those offered by eBay) are also Second Price auctions; bidders outbid each other, and can use proxy bids so that they don’t have to bid again when outbid. The winning price is the second highest of all bids plus a small increment. A drawback of this kind of auctions is “sniping”—expert bidders use automated services to place a bid during the last second of the auction, depriving less savvy bidders of their chance to bid and producing an inefficient outcome.

Let’s compare all these approaches to the Simultaneous Ascending Price Clock Auction that ICANN chose for their Last Resort Auctions, and that the participants chose for all Applicant Auctions held so far as well. As in the Second Price sealed bid auction, you can enter the highest amount you are willing to pay, once. You can then walk away knowing if your bid was the highest, you win, without overpaying as you would in a First Price auction. And as in a live auction or an eBay style auction, you don’t have to disclose to anyone how much you were willing to pay. The auction runs online, and there is no risk of sniping, because there is no benefit to placing your bid at the last moment. Finally, you don’t have to make a big decision up front—as the auction progresses, you can decide along the way if you would like to continue bidding, and you even get some feedback on how much demand there is for the domains for sale in the auctions.

Distribution of the winner’s payment

One critical issue related to any auction design is the disposition of the winner’s payment. For ICANN’s Last Resort Auction, the answer is clear: ICANN keeps the money, leaving the issue of what ICANN does with it to be addressed later by the ICANN community.

For private auctions, the money can be distributed among applicants who did not win, either in equal shares or proportionally to the amount bid. In the proportional case, your payout increases if you bid more—this can incent people to bid more than they otherwise would, potentially resulting in higher payments and inefficient outcomes. Payment in equal shares means that even if you bid $0 in the auction, you receive an equal share of the winner’s payment.

Opinions differ regarding the fairness of this—one argument is that each applicant for a gTLD has an equal right to it, so they all should be paid the same for giving up that right. We believe that equal payments will result in a more efficient outcome, and that winners will pay less than they would at a Last Resort Auction.

Another idea some applicants have discussed is to contribute some or all of the winner’s payment to one or more third parties of the applicants’ choice (e.g. charity, industry association, etc.). For example, with a three-applicant gTLD, the rule could be that each of the two applicants who didn’t win receives a set minimum amount, and the remainder is transferred to the third party. This would compensate the sellers for their time and effort put into the gTLD with a third party benefitting as well.

Settlement

A third aspect unique to private auctions is how to ensure that the results of the auctions become reality—how can the winner trust that in exchange for paying, it will become the sole applicant, and how can the others trust that they will be paid for withdrawing?

An essential element of this is the bidding deposits each participant makes. ICANN requires this, too—the main purpose of the bidding deposit is to ensure that applicants can’t bid up the price, win, and then not pay. Such behavior can expose how much the other bidders were willing to pay, completely undermining the second price nature of the auction.

The bidding deposit is usually a fixed percentage of the highest amount the bidder can bid—for example, 10%. Some applicants worry that this gives an indication of how much they are willing to pay. This is one of the arguments for setting a maximum deposit that allows unlimited bidding.

Another element of a settlement procedure is how long the winner’s payment stays in escrow. One possibility is to pay out the non-winning applicants once ICANN has announced the withdrawal of all non-winning applications in the auction. The rationale is that at this point, the winner has become the sole remaining applicant—and the privilege to be in this position is what the winner is paying for. This is the approach that found a consensus for all of the 21 auctions that we are aware of to date—but of course, this is a policy that can be set by applicants on a per-contention set basis.

Summary

We have now covered the most commonly discussed different ways in which private auctions can be conducted. The three different elements (auction design, disposition of auction revenues, and settlement) can all be evaluated separately.

Some auction designs are harder to implement than others (for example, an ascending clock auction requires specialized software), but for the most part, all providers can offer the same auction designs.

Disposition of revenues and some of the settlement terms are a matter of negotiation and consensus finding between applicants.

For all three elements, but in particular for the settlement process, the auction provider’s experience in settling private gTLD auctions is an important factor.

We hope gTLD applicants find this article helpful in structuring their thinking on which approach works best for them, and for communicating this to the other applicants in the contention set.

Ultimately, the most important success factor is unanimous participation, and clear communication will help build a consensus more quickly. The Last Resort Auctions are happening soon—there is not much time left.

The last opportunity to participate in the Applicant Auction before ICANN’s first auction is February 18th. If you are interested in participating, please contact us immediately—the cut-off for participation is January 31st.

By Sheel Mohnot, Project Director, Applicant Auction

Filed Under

Comments

Mechanism Design Alex Tajirian  –  Jan 27, 2014 9:08 PM

In a 2008 post on this forum I proposed that a team of experts in auction mechanism design be formed (see http://www.circleid.com/posts/icanns_allocation_method_for_new_tlds/). Already, the non-synchronous timing of auctions has resulted in disadvantages to some winners, who will pass part of the additional costs to gTLD buyers.

Alex - It was good to re-read Peter Cramton  –  Jan 28, 2014 11:26 AM

Alex - It was good to re-read your excellent post from 2008 advocating careful auction design by a team of experts that understands the theory behind the design alternatives and can draw from past experience. We very much agree; and the design for the Applicant Auction reflects my experience from 20 years of auction design as well as that proposed by ICANN's auction consultants, since the Applicant Auction is extremely similar. We also tested the Applicant Auction design and the best alternatives in the lab and in the field. Regarding the timing, yes, we also think that it's best for everyone to auction many contention sets simultaneously. Since we run almost all of the private auctions for resolving contention, applicants working with us have lots of choices and flexibility for dates - without having to be part of a one-off single sealed bid auction that requires them to make a commitment without any insight on other developments in the market.

Other Options for Private Contention Resoluton Monte Cahn  –  Jan 27, 2014 10:01 PM

Thank you Sheel for posting these options.  Ironically, Innovative auctions is now offering options that RightOfTheDot has been presenting to applicants for almost 2 years now and your post is very similar to an email that we have distributed to all applicants in contention since the last two ICANN Conferences.

With that said, I would like to add that RightOfTheDot.com will be completing the industry’s first Single Sealed Second Price Auction, which is scheduled on Feb. 7th. We will be providing both single sealed bid auctions as well as ascending clock auctions through our exclusive relationship with Heritage Auctions (an $8 Billion world wide industry leading auction provider) at various times throughout the year beginning in March.

We will be scheduling auctions around the needs of each contention set and scheduling these based on the consensus of the contention set rather than posting a date and deadline and hoping applicants will come.  We realize that most are still not ready and weighing their options, preparing their budgets and working towards resolution in a well thought through manner.  So there are no initial deadlines or cut-off dates when working with us.  We will also perform single contention set auctions for as little as 2 participants or as many coinciding contention sets as applicants would like to resolve at one time.  So there is no minimum or maximum in the number of contentions sets we will resolve at any one time and we wont schedule auctions around having to have a minimum number of contentions to resolve. 

We also came up with the concept of payouts going to charity or third parties / industry associations and / or the non winning bidders (in any distribution manner) or a combination of both. For this option, funds can go to non winning bidders and charities or industry associations as a combined option.  This concept was designed around some of the larger public companies that expressed concerns where 100% of the funds would go to non winning participants.  Again we feel this is up to each contention set and the needs of each participant to efficiently resolve contention and move onto their respective business.

We also welcome the opportunity to work with any and all contention sets to help you resolve contention prior to when the last resort auctions are scheduled.  Our fees are also generally lower than others providing this service and inclusive of all escrow fees.  Lastly we can customize just about any type of auction solution needed to resolve contention in very short periods of time.

Anyone interested can reach me directly at .(JavaScript must be enabled to view this email address)

Comment Title:

  Notify me of follow-up comments

We encourage you to post comments and engage in discussions that advance this post through relevant opinion, anecdotes, links and data. If you see a comment that you believe is irrelevant or inappropriate, you can report it using the link at the end of each comment. Views expressed in the comments do not represent those of CircleID. For more information on our comment policy, see Codes of Conduct.

CircleID Newsletter The Weekly Wrap

More and more professionals are choosing to publish critical posts on CircleID from all corners of the Internet industry. If you find it hard to keep up daily, consider subscribing to our weekly digest. We will provide you a convenient summary report once a week sent directly to your inbox. It's a quick and easy read.

Related

Topics

DNS

Sponsored byDNIB.com

Cybersecurity

Sponsored byVerisign

Brand Protection

Sponsored byCSC

New TLDs

Sponsored byRadix

Threat Intelligence

Sponsored byWhoisXML API

IPv4 Markets

Sponsored byIPv4.Global

Domain Names

Sponsored byVerisign